If the Obamacare “tax” exceeds the cost of insurance, it becomes a unconstitutional “penalty”

In NFIB v. Sebelius, the Chief Justice applied a saving construction to the Affordable Care Act’s penalty, and treated it as a tax, to uphold its constitutionality. (Thom Lambert has a great piece in Regulation Magazine on this topic). But, the Chief Justice placed limitations on the application of the saving construction. The first such limitation stated that because the cost of the “tax” is less than the cost of insurance, a person has a legitimate choice, and there is no coercion:

The same analysis here suggests that the shared responsibility payment may for constitutional purposes be considered a tax, not a penalty: First, for most Americans the amount due will be far less than the price of insurance, and, by statute, it can never be more. FN It may often be a reasonable financial decision to make the payment rather than purchase insurance, unlike the “prohibitory” financial punishment in Drexel Furniture. 259 U. S., at 37.

FN In 2016, for example, individuals making $35,000 a year are expected to owe the IRS about $60 for any month in which they do not have health insurance. Someone with an annual income of $100,000 a year would likely owe about $200. The price of a qualifying insurance policy is projected to be around $400 per month. See D. Newman, CRS Report for Congress, Individual Mandate and Related Information Re-quirements Under PPACA 7, and n. 25 (2011).

Though it is not entirely correct that the “tax” can never be more than the cost of insurance.

The relevant statute is (our favorite) 26 U.S. Code § 5000A. The penalty starts at $95 a month, and will increase to $325 in 2015,  $695 in 2016, and will grow with inflation after that. It’s expected to hit $800 a month by 2023.   For wealthier Americans, the penalty (when fully phased in) will be even greater, between 1% and 2.5% of income.

(B) Percentage of income

An amount equal to the following percentage of the excess of the taxpayer’s household income for the taxable year over the amount of gross income specified in section 6012 (a)(1) with respect to the taxpayer for the taxable year:
(i) 1.0 percent for taxable years beginning in 2014.
(ii) 2.0 percent for taxable years beginning in 2015.
(iii) 2.5 percent for taxable years beginning after 2015.

Though, this penalty is capped by statute.

The amount of the penalty imposed by this section on any taxpayer for any taxable year with respect to failures described in subsection (b)(1) shall be . . .  amount equal to the national average premium for qualified health plans which have a bronze level of coverage, provide coverage for the applicable family size involved, and are offered through Exchanges for plan years beginning in the calendar year with or within which the taxable year ends.

In plain English, this says that the amount of the penalty (not “tax” in case anyone bothered to read the law Congress passed) will not exceed the “national average premium for qualified health plans which have a bronze level of coverage.” So the Chief is wrong to say that the amount will always be less. Why? Because the cost of bronze plans varies by states. In some states it may be more expensive than other. Due to the very nature of an average, in some states it will be above the average, and in some states it will be below the average. In no way can the prices be the same nationwide.

Now it may be true for “most Americans” (those above the average) but not for all Americans (below the average). In fact, the wealthiest Americans, who live in states with the lowest bronze-priced plans, will almost certainly be faced with a false choice–the “tax” will be more expensive than the cost of insurance. 2% of their income will almost certainly be more than the cost of the cheapest bronze plan.

Let’s do some math.  CBO projects that the average national bronze plan will be $5,000 a year in 2016. Therefore, if the penalty would be capped at $5,000 a year, who would pay a $5,000 penalty? An individual earning $200,000 a year (200,000 * .025 = 5,000). But what if the cheapest available plan that qualifies under the Affordable Care Act in that person’s state is less than $5,000 a year? Say the cheapest bronze plan is $4,000 a year.  Because the statute pegs the penalty to the national average, rather than a local average–and it is impossible to buy across state lines–for some wealthier individuals, there is no meaningful choice.

By it’s very terms, this would seem to run headlong into the Chief Justice’s saving construction, which misstated the nature of the statutory cap. At this point, it would no longer be a “constitutional tax” but an “unconstitutional penalty.”

Certainly, somewhere, there is some wealthy person who stands to pay more under the Obamacare “tax” than insurance would cost. Such a challenge could assert that there are limits on the scope of the penalty. 

Cross-Posted at JoshBlackman.com.

Josh Blackman is an Assistant Professor of Law at the South Texas College of Law who specializes in constitutional law, the United States Supreme Court, and the intersection of law and technology. He is the author of Unprecedented: The Constitutional Challenge to Obamacare and also blogs at JoshBlackman.com.

About the Author

Comments

  1. R Richard Schweitzer says

    An interesting thing about the Roberts opinion is that this summer what overrides the Holmes conclusion that the power to tax is the power to destroy.

    In effect, the court has now ruled that the power to tax cannot be used as a power to course.

    If the 2 are to be reconciled, the citizen and his enterprise may be destroyed, but not coerced.

    • djf says

      “The power to tax involves the power to destroy” was written by Chief Justice Marshall in McCulloch v Maryland.

  2. nobody.really says

    What difference would it make if the penalty/tax were larger than the cost of insurance? If you find the tax too onerous, just buy the insurance: problem solved.

    That is, unless you have a contentious objection to buying the insurance. In that case, under RFRA, arguably the ACA would need to pass through the “strict scrutiny” sieve – and the size of the tax would have to be narrowly tailored (i.e., no larger than necessary) to achieve government’s purposes.

    Now, clearly, if a tax were large enough to pay for insurance in a commercial market, it would be large enough to achieve the government’s purposes. But potentially a smaller tax would suffice – maybe the price of insurance at wholesale. But who would bear the burden of making such calculations – the plaintiff or the government?

    • gabe says

      para #1) the difference is that i may not want to buy any insurance; or i want to buy what i used to have but must pay a “cadillac” tax on it. Why is it any of the governments business, anyway?

      para #2) Why must my personal choices be subject to the whims of the Black robes and their strict scrutiny probings? (ouch, that hurts!!!)

      para #3) I suppose the first sentence is Ok, if one supports the contention that the government has a right to pursue such purposes – many of us do not!
      As to the second sentence, gee, isn’t that gracious of the powers that be – to “allow” us to pay at wholesale.Sentence 3 – I suppose the government would want to make such calculations as this would allow it to justify adding another 20, 000 “experts” to its payroll and complete the stranglehold it is placing around the throats of the insurance industry.

  3. libertarian jerry says

    What is amazing is the can of worms that was opened when the 16th Amendment (Income Tax) was put into law 100 years ago.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

You may use these HTML tags and attributes: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <cite> <code> <del datetime=""> <em> <i> <q cite=""> <strike> <strong>