• About
  • Contact
  • Staff

Law & Liberty

A Project of Liberty Fund

  • Home
  • Blog
  • Liberty Law Forum
  • Podcasts
  • Book Reviews

June 26, 2017|Federal Reserve, Inflation, John Maynard Keynes, monetary policy

Ending the Fed’s Permanent Inflation Policy

by James R. Rogers|6 Comments

dollar

The Federal Reserve Board seeks to maintain an inflation rate around two percent per year. While this rate might sound low for older types who remember double-digit inflation rates in the late 70s and early 80s, and a rate of 5.4 percent as recently as 1990, why tolerate, let alone seek to sustain, any inflation at all? Why not seek to establish zero inflation and stable prices? After all, even an inflation rate of only two percent a year means nominal prices still double every 36 years. And while people can and do broadly adjust their behavior in the face of anticipated inflation, it’s not a seamless process. Inflation distorts people’s economic decisions, whether as producers or consumers, labor or capital, and so imposes costs on us all.

The Fed aims to maintain a two-percent inflation rate because it fears a lower inflation rate would deprive it of the monetary policy tools it needs in case of recession. As Ben Bernanke explained at a 2013 press conference: “If you have zero inflation, you’re very close to the deflation zone and nominal interest rates will be so low that it would be very difficult to respond fully to recessions. And so historical experiences suggested that 2 percent is an appropriate balance.” Basically, the Fed intentionally seeks to create and sustain a positive inflation rate in order, in turn, to sustain nominal interest rates higher than would exist with zero inflation.

Economists call it the problem of the “zero lower bound.” To wit, if nominal interest rates move into negative territory, that is, move below zero, then people would naturally go into cash to avoid losing money deposited in banks. This effectively rules out the ability of the Fed to set interest rates below zero.

I might pause to note there exists a sizeable contingent of macroeconomists skeptical of the efficacy of interest rate manipulation as a means of responding to recessions, particularly among those sympathetic with Real Business Cycle theory. But Keynesianism never lost its appeal, particularly among policy makers (and journalists), if for no other reason than it gives them at least the appearance of doing something in response to a recession. Whether justified or not, the 2008 recession rejuvenated confidence in Keynesianism in the popular mind. And, frankly, a burst of theoretical work among “New Keynesian” economists (much of which significantly predated the 2008 recession), increased academic interest in Keynesian economics more generally. This is something of a turn. Twenty-five years ago Keynesianism was on the ropes in the academy, with its reputation in tatters as New Keynesians tinkered around the edges to save what they could of the theory.

But whether efficacious or not in enabling the Fed to respond to recessions, even an inflation rate of two percent imposes costs on society. Hence the desire among economists for a century or more to think of ways to “break through the lower zero bound.” The benefit of doing so would mean the Fed could aim to maintain price stability – zero inflation – without at the same time ceding lower interest rates as a tool to fight recessions. What “breaking through the zero bound” means, however, is that the Fed must be able to set negative interest rates, that is, it must be able to set interest rates lower than zero.

But the trick with that is preventing people from holding cash when interest rates go below zero. So how to do that?

First, I might note that I’m unsure the proffered cures are better than the disease. Still, price stability is such an attractive goal, and Keynesian sentiment so ensconced among policy makers, that it’s worth seeing if there’s a reasonable path to achieving the former on grounds even Keynesians would agree with.

Different modes of deterring cash holdings have been around for a while. In his General Theory, Keynes discussed the earlier work of Silvio Gesell. In 1906, Gesell suggested creating a stamp for paper money, akin to today’s tobacco stamp. As with the tobacco stamp, the money stamp would levy a tax on paper currency. The purpose of the tax would be to deter people from going into cash when interest rates dropped below zero.

So, too, proposals to move to a cashless economy – money would be electronic only – have generally been floated to reduce crime. Additionally, however, a system of paperless money would also allow negative interest rates, and so circumvents the problem of the lower bound. (If money is held only in electronic form, then there’s nothing physical to withdraw if interest rates move below zero. If one wanted to physicalize electronic money, one would have to spend it on things, which is precisely the Keynesian policy prescription to respond to recessions.)

Neither a stamp tax on paper currency nor the elimination of paper currency seems political feasible. Indeed, while paperless currency is discussed more today than a stamp tax, in a world of shrinking privacy and increasing governmental (and non-governmental) snooping, it’s not only criminals who worry about the consequences of a world in which all transactions can be traced electronically, because money is only electronic.

Economists Miles Kimball and Ruchir Agarwal propose a hybrid policy possibility in an IMF working paper in which paper money continues to exist in tandem with electronic money. This avoids the privacy concerns of moving to a wholly paperless monetary system. In the dual system they propose, the central bank could manipulate the exchange rate between paper money and electronic money, and in so doing the Fed could lower the interest rate for paper money below zero. While preserving the existence of paper money, the critical feature of the proposal is that electronic money would be the sole base currency, thereby allowing the depreciation of paper money below face value when needed for the economy.

Needless to say, this feature would take some getting used to. Nonetheless, what the trick allows is the Fed to deter people from holding paper money, but only when needed to fight a recession. Unlike today’s policy, however, these actions would be activated only during recessions. In contrast, today’s policy requires permanent and continuous inflation of the money supply, even if at a low level, just so that the interest-rate tool can be used when the occasional recession requires it.

Still, the hybrid proposal has its own difficulties, and I am unsure that this policy is any more politically feasible than a stamp tax for currency, or a move to a cashless society. Miles Kimball, however, travels the world in an attempt to persuade smaller countries to give the proposal a test whirl. In any event, the recognition among Keynesians of the social cost of pursuing a permanent inflationary policy is refreshing, and the desire to remedy it is encouraging.

James R. Rogers

James Rogers is associate professor of political science at Texas A&M University, and is a fellow with the Institute for Science, Technology and Public Policy at the Bush School of Government and Public Service. He also served as editor of the Journal of Theoretical Politics from 2006 through 2013.

About the Author

On the Road
Another Wrongful Conviction Case

Recent Popular Posts

  • Popular
  • Today Week Month All
  • Superman and the Drive-By Media April 20, 2018
  • Chappaquiddick Rescues the Truth: Kopechne Needn’t Have Died April 20, 2018
  • Reading the State of Britain with Roger Scruton April 19, 2018
  • Explaining the New Illiberal Liberalism April 18, 2018
  • The Constitution and Executive Privilege July 12, 2012
Ajax spinner

Related Posts

Related

Comments

  1. Wayne Abernathy says

    June 26, 2017 at 8:01 am

    This policy is founded on the oft-disproven conceit that any group of people can overtime outsmart the markets. Also notice that the Federal Reserve policy for the last several years has accomplished what Caesars, kings, Senates, and governments of many stripes have normally sought to do when they had control of the money supply, i.e. use it to plunder the population in general, often through some means of debasing the currency. The near zero-rate interest rate policy of the Fed has been a huge transfer of wealth from savers to subsidize government borrowing. Inflation is another means by which governments impose hidden taxes on their people.

    Reply
  2. Alan McIntire says

    June 27, 2017 at 8:59 am

    From Keynes “Wealth of Nations”, the idea is to promote higher employment. Wage earners may not accept the lower wage leading to full employment. With inflation, the workers are actually accepting the lower wages and you’re getting full employment. The rationale is that the workers are too stupid to realize that they are being paid in
    inflated dollars and ARE getting the lower wage.

    Reply
    • Alan McIntire says

      June 27, 2017 at 6:20 pm

      Sorry, I meant “General Theory”, not Adam Smith’s book

      Reply
  3. Matthew Kilburn says

    June 27, 2017 at 10:11 am

    For better or worse, a digital currency does not solve the “hard asset” problem. Virtually any non-wastable good can serve as a store of value. We see this plenty already with members of the tinfoil hat brgade who hoard gold as they make continual doom and gloom prophecies.

    Reply
  4. Paul Binotto says

    June 27, 2017 at 4:09 pm

    Going Cashless in a Classless Society:

    Conversion to a paperless money economy or a stamp tax policy would seem to have the potential of inflicting a financial hardship on a segment of low income wage earners who quickly convert paychecks into cash because they are unable to maintain minimum balance requirements or to absorb banking (minimum) balance and transaction fees, that make holding a checking and/or savings account feasible.

    For this segment of wage earners, even under the hybrid policy, it may be a matter of “heads I win, tails you lose”; either lose value of paper money, or lose money on minimum balance and transactional banking fees.

    Perhaps the author could address whether this is an actual concern, and if so, what the potential impact would be on low wage earners who find it more feasible to convert earnings to cash.

    Of course, the income taxing authorities would be a big winner in a cashless economy, as it would become very difficult to work “under the table” without reporting.

    Reply

Trackbacks

  1. Ending Inflation? | azmytheconomics says:
    July 7, 2017 at 6:04 pm

    […] A response to: http://www.libertylawsite.org/2017/06/26/ending-the-feds-permanent-inflation-policy/ […]

    Reply

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Book Reviews

John C. Calhoun, Madisonian Manqué

by Thomas W. Merrill

His institutional innovations were geared toward preserving slavery.

Read More

The Road to Iranian Democracy

by Luma Simms

The suppression of the Green Movement last time around widened the gulf between Iran’s elite and its people.

Read More

Podcasts

The Solid Ground of Mere Civility: A Conversation with Teresa Bejan

A discussion with Teresa M. Bejan

Teresa Bejan discusses with us how early modern debates over religious toleration are an example of how we can disagree well.

Read More

Leading a Worthy Life in a Scattered Time: A Conversation with Leon Kass

A discussion with Leon Kass

Leon Kass discusses Leading a Worthy Life.

Read More

Eric Voegelin Studies: A Conversation with Charles Embry

A discussion with Charles Embry

What did “Don’t immanentize the eschaton!” really mean? An intro podcast on the formidable mind of Eric Voegelin.

Read More

Republican Virtue, Interrupted: A Conversation with Frank Buckley

A discussion with F.H. Buckley

The real conflict in our politics centers on reforming massive levels of public corruption.

Read More

Recent Posts

  • Chappaquiddick Rescues the Truth: Kopechne Needn’t Have Died

    Mary Jo Kopechne perished not because Ted Kennedy crashed his car, but because the legacy was more important than telling the authorities she was in it.
    by Nathaniel Peters

  • Superman and the Drive-By Media

    Prime territory for Clark Kent to investigate: the biased and superficial work done by our most prominent journalists.
    by Mark Judge

  • Partisan Gerrymandering and The Original Meaning of “Election”

    States are responsible for the nature of elections: without a strong historical argument to the contrary, partisan gerrymandering is constitutional.
    by Mike Rappaport

  • Reading the State of Britain with Roger Scruton

    In Where We Are, Roger Scruton helps us see Britain's possible futures, but the question remains: is he pessimistic enough?
    by Theodore Dalrymple

  • Is Partisan Gerrymandering of Congressional Elections Unconstitutional Under the Original Meaning?

    Professor Ned Foley argues that the Constitution limits congressional gerrymandering. Why is this?
    by Mike Rappaport

Blogroll

  • Acton PowerBlog
  • Cafe Hayek
  • Cato@Liberty
  • Claremont
  • Congress Shall Make No Law
  • EconLog
  • Fed Soc Blog
  • First Things
  • Hoover
  • ISI First Principles Journal
  • Legal Theory Blog
  • Marginal Revolution
  • Pacific Legal Liberty Blog
  • Point of Law
  • Power Line
  • Professor Bainbridge
  • Ricochet
  • Right Reason
  • Spengler
  • The American
  • The Beacon Blog
  • The Foundry
  • The Originalism Blog
  • The Public Discourse
  • University Bookman
  • Via Meadia
  • Volokh

Archives

  • All Posts & Publications
  • Book Reviews
  • Liberty Forum
  • Liberty Law Blog
  • Liberty Law Talk

About

Law and Liberty’s focus is on the content, status, and development of law in the context of republican and limited government and the ways that liberty and law and law and liberty mutually reinforce the other. This site brings together serious debate, commentary, essays, book reviews, interviews, and educational material in a commitment to the first principles of law in a free society. Law and Liberty considers a range of foundational and contemporary legal issues, legal philosophy, and pedagogy.

  • Home
  • About
  • Staff
  • Contact
  • Archive

Apple App Store
Google Play Store

© 2018 Liberty Fund, Inc.

Subscribe
Get Law and Liberty's latest content delivered to you daily
  • This field is for validation purposes and should be left unchanged.
No thanks